百家乐怎么玩-澳门百家乐官网娱乐城网址_网上百家乐是不是真的_全讯网888 (中国)·官方网站

Reading Colonies—Property and Control of the British Far East

Author / Editor
HKD208.00
In stock
Add to Wish List
By 1945, everywhere one looked in the Far East the British Empire was being openly questioned or was failing outright. Yet in the previous century, the British had been the pre-eminent imperial power from Weihaiwei to North Borneo.

Reading Colonies: Property and Control of the British Far East investigates how the British held on for so long. Rent control legislation, and other measures of property law such as land improvement opportunities, are nominated as key tools used to frustrate decolonization in most Eastern colonies. British colonial administrations tried long and hard to inhibit the dialectical discord between their colonial hierarchism and local forms of nationalism with the prompts and plaudits of property policy. In cases where indigenous landlordism masqueraded as patriotism, independence came quickly (Ceylon and Burma). Where public housing established itself as a key post-war plank of social policy, freedom from British rule was a more gradual affair (British Malaya and Hong Kong).

This study concludes that British colonial regimes did not offer a share of their industrial modernity to stay at the apex of political power, but readily adjusted old-style landlordism to keep nationalist usurpers at bay.
ISBN
978-962-937-297-2
Pub. Date
Dec 1, 2016
Weight
0.45kg
Paperback
248 pages
Dimension
140 x 241 mm
The genesis of this book was in a series of conversations I had at Shandong University (Weihai) with Professor Jiang Ming of the law school there. An eminent sociologist, and the son of a re-educated Kuomintang railway man, he expounded on a remarkable idea. In breaks between table-tennis rallies, he demonstrated that China would have made it to modernity without Western help. The Kuomintang government would have cleaned up its notorious corruption. The bounties of imperial examination, customs duty, and tribute would have been pluralized. Less well-known veins of Confucianism would have been politically deployed to describe a harmonious relationship of the state to its citizens through respect for intellectuals, including scientists. Fiscally disciplined and developmental in outlook, modern China would have been born. Unless for its internecine squabbling, modern China — fiscally disciplined and developmental in outlook — would trace its birth to 1912 and see its infancy over the 1930s. And all without industrialization.

Jiang’s view was speculative in a vein that Marxists truly hate. But it did not quite feel like “what if” history. He maintained that China had been steadily gathering the ingredients for a great prudential republic even after the West intervened in its affairs decisively to make it dependent on opium in 1841. It would not be a democracy in the Westminster vein or especially controlled by an aggressively accumulative industrial base in the vein of, say, the Teutonic type. It would be a republic of railways and filial workshops, with a central government radiating its civic spokes outwards to secure, with reason, conflicting impulses of ethnicity and religion in a fixed orbit around the Nanjing metropole. By building flood levies and rolling out telegraph lines, it would earn a reputation for measured benevolence. The ascent of Sun Yat-sen to the provisional presidency in 1912 augured many of these things. He was a Christian, a man of science, who was devoted to the overthrow of the feudal imperial family and the modernization of government by opening up political opportunity.

Postcolonial historians have a couple of options in how they view the Far Eastern past. Needless to say, the self-governing Chinese republic of railways is not prominent among them. Neither has China been seen as a tightly contested semi-colonial space. Best aligned to the tenor of this work, has been the new retrospective school led by Chibber which has questioned why industrialization failed in India compared to other places in North East Asia and answered it by pointing to discord between objectives of state developmentalists and local capitalists. The radical positivist school led by Stoler contains no developmental argument. It has subjectively viewed the colonial world as a loose collection of inferior places with colonial rulers given to administrative anxiety about indigenous nationalism and inter-racialism. These were to be negated with bouts of racist violence, frogmarching or co-option, if that seemed to work better. To the old structural school, overseen by the likes of Hobsbawm, colonies were extrusions of bottled up European capital. They were merely supplicant syndications of British nationalism. Enriching the metropole via involuntary consumer trade, or slave labour for manufacturing, colonies were garrisoned replications of mother country social class whether under palm or pine. Colonies progressed their development agendas according to metropolitan, not local, needs.

Chapter 1         The Limits of Theory

Chapter 2         Reading Colonies via Property Policy

Chapter 3         Judicial Autonomy and Post-War Rent Control

Chapter 4         Property as Anti-Nationalism or Failing Geopolitics

Chapter 5         Reading Capital, Reading Colonies

Chapter 6         Codas

百家乐官网群到shozo网| 新锦江百家乐官网娱乐场| 石阡县| 百家乐官网1元投注| 威尼斯人娱乐官网| 百家乐官网2号机器投注技巧| 电子百家乐规则| 金樽百家乐官网的玩法技巧和规则 | 美女百家乐官网的玩法技巧和规则 | 网络百家乐官网会输钱的多吗 | 威尼斯人娱乐城--老品牌值得您信赖| 百家乐官网永利娱乐平台| 皇冠网投| 澳门百家乐网址| 百家乐官网小游戏开发| 番禺百家乐电器店| 日照市| 大发888游戏官方下载客户端 | 玩百家乐官网技巧看路| 嘉年华百家乐官网的玩法技巧和规则| 国际娱百家乐的玩法技巧和规则| 百家乐官网如何买大小| 德州扑克葫芦| 温州百家乐官网的玩法技巧和规则 | 大发888国际游戏平台| 百家乐板路| 哪里有百家乐官网赌博网站| 南通热线棋牌中心| 百家乐博彩平台| 百家乐官网筹码防伪定制| 欧博线上娱乐| 德州扑克筹码定做| 大发888 娱乐场| 百家乐游戏试| 百家乐澳门百家乐澳门赌场| 玩百家乐官网去哪个平台好| 免佣百家乐的玩法| 百家乐官网平的概率| 百家娱乐| 百家乐六合彩| 网页百家乐官网的玩法技巧和规则 |